Mikhail Bakunin, the
founder of modern anarchism, though unsystematic, was a most
prescient thinker.
Long before Ludwig von
Mises and Friedrich Hayek Bakunin warned that no “group of
intellectuals no matter how great their genius” could “understand
the plethora of interests, attitudes and activities” needed to
centrally plan and administer the rational allocation of preferences
in a modern industrial economy.
The anarchist origin of
this critique of central planning is just about universally ignored
precisely because its neoliberal variant, which is crucial to the
legitimacy of contemporary economic policy, claims a monopoly on
rationality and efficiency.
It is often said that
anarchism is an irrational way in which to organise a modern
industrial society, and this argument is presented by serious minded
critics as the most forceful against anarchist arrangements.
Anarchism is a doctrine
for the warm hearted romantic, not the hard headed rationalist, we
are told by those who possess the cynicism of the sophisticated.
One of the more well
known dismissals of the “naive optimism” of anarchist thought and
practice, that due to James Joll, observed that “mass production
and consumption and large scale industry under a centralised
direction, whether capitalist or socialist, have, whatever one may
think about them, become the characteristic forms of western society
and of the newly emergent industrial countries elsewhere.”
Anarchism swims against
the tide for “the basic assumptions of anarchism are all contrary
to the development of large scale industry and of mass production and
consumption” so “for this reason, much anarchist thinking seemed
to be based on a romantic, backward looking vision of an idealised
past society of artisans and peasants, and on a total rejection of
the realities of twentieth century social and economic organisation.”
The argument is an
intriguing one for it presupposes that there is a necessary
correlation between rationality and centralised modes of economic and
political organisation, and the only defence offered for this
presupposition is that is how matters are currently arranged.
The mere existence of
centralised modes of organisation imply their rationality.
The reality, and
necessity, of centralised modes of organisation is one of the charges
that some Marxists continue to make against anarchist thought.
Certainly Marxists would not disagree with Joll regarding present
realities for, as related in The Communist Manifesto, capitalism “has
agglomerated population, centralized the means of production, and has
concentrated property in a few hands. The necessary consequence of
this was political centralization.”
Marxists, crucially for
our present purposes, have tended to argue that this centralisation
is an historical stage that civilisation must traverse for the advent
of production for surplus, and its underlying productive basis, make
communism possible in a modern setting.
One of the reasons why
the Bolsheviks ruled via the iron hand of the state was because they
sought to amass capital, especially at the expense of the peasantry,
so that Soviet society could pass through this necessary stage of
industrial development upon the road to communism.
One may accuse Lenin
and Stalin of many a thing but surely “naive optimism” be not one
of them.
The last thirty to
thirty five years has witnessed a one sided class war waged against
the working classes by the corporate elites and the states to which
they are tightly connected.
This attack on the
population, dressed in the garb of neoliberal theory, has to no small
degree been justified on grounds of rationality and efficiency. From
“free trade” to labour market deregulation the market has been
unleashed for the mantra has it that the market can ensure the
rational production, allocation and distribution of resources. Behind
the scenes, in the meanwhile, corporations derive benefit from state
tutelage whilst the working classes are subject to its disciplining
rigours.
A key argument made by
neoliberals, following on from the socialist calculation debate, is
that market based societies alone are rational or efficient
allocators of resources because of their highly decentralised nature.
The panoply of buyers and sellers operating in markets incorporate
all available information needed to ensure the rational allocation of
preferences. That information is reflected in market prices.
The most graphic, and
most intellectually bankrupt, application of this doctrine is the
efficient market hypothesis which asserts that capital market prices
incorporate all available information regarding future capital
earnings. This means that market prices are rational and based on
economic fundamentals, rather than manias, irrational exuberance and
the like. Given that it is via capital markets that investment is
made in capitalist society there exists a strong tendency toward the
rationality of investment and the allocation of capital.
The link drawn here,
intriguingly, was one between rationality and decentralisation, yet
it is the decentralised aspect to anarchism that makes it “naive
optimism.”
The reality of
financial market instability, most especially the manic driven cycles
of boom and bust, demonstrate that capital market prices cannot be
reflective of the rational processing of all available information
regarding future earnings. This fact is of no small moment as the
Chernobyl scale meltdown of financial markets and the resulting
misallocation of capital sits at the core of the global financial
crisis.
We all know that
investors and speculators spend a great deal of time hunting for
information prior to taking a position in capital markets. If capital
market prices incorporated all available information such activity
would not be necessary so the fact that it occurs, and that upon a
large scale, suggests that markets in fact are quite inefficient.
The purported
rationality of markets, despite the grim reality, is neither utopian
nor naively optimistic. To the contrary, neoliberal policy making
continues to frame our age.
A centrally planned
economy cannot possibly incorporate all available information, the
neoliberals told us, and we are told that only they told us, for the
central apparatus of the state cannot possibly possess the
information needed to ensure a rational allocation of goods and
services.
Mikhail Bor, a Soviet
central planner, observed in the 1960s that “the planned
organisation of the economy in the USSR allows for the rational use
of labour in the interest of the whole of society.” Similar
sentiments applied to other sectors of the economy.The expectation
was raised that advances in mathematical modelling, made by possible
by supercomputing, linear programming and cybernetics, would make
central planning yet more rational.
Such be a species of
“naive optimism.” But one of no small moment as the travails of
the Soviet economy were used to buttress the case made for the
rationality of markets in the advanced industrial societies. The
failure of Soviet central planning added impetus to the next, post
cold war, phase of the neoliberal offensive on society. Alternative
critiques, to the extent even addressed, could be dismissed as naïve
optimism.
Ours is a society
dominated by large corporations whose highly hierarchical and
centralised systems of management plan the production, allocation,
and distribution of goods and services. As Alfred Chandler observed
“in many sectors of the economy the visible hand of management
replaced what Adam Smith referred to as the invisible hand of market
forces.”
It should be stressed
that these visible hands are quite centralised and hierarchical. Ours
is an economy composed of strategic alliances between connected
islands of centralised economic and political power.
Interestingly Chandler
argued that in the domain of consumption market dynamics still apply,
but even here one must be cautious. The vast public relations
industry, through highly crafted propaganda, plays a very important
role in shaping the pattern of consumption, and this is done from
cradle to grave twenty four hours a day, seven days a week.
Information asymmetries
are endemic to corporate dominated societies for there is much that
the visible hand of management knows that other hands do not. When
there exist asymmetries in the possession of power so there must
exist asymmetries in the possession of information. When asymmetries
of information exist within markets then the misallocation of
resources follows, and so we get, often colossal, market failure.
Markets have the
tendency to encourage the central agglomeration of capital as they
evolve with respect to time so this is an inherent tendency to any
market based society.
Anarchism, at least its
traditional left wing variants of anarchist communism and
anarchosyndicalism, is a vision of a modern industrial society that
is highly decentralised.
The vision is of a
society that consists of a decentralised federation of worker owned
and managed enterprises and that, for anarchist communists,
distributes and remunerates production upon the basis of need.
The planning decisions
of these enterprises would account for the production, distribution
and allocation of resources.
These enterprises would
be non hierarchical and non authoritarian. That is, their management
would be based on principles of participatory democracy so therefore
all economic agents would be managers involved in the framing of
economic decisions. There would, thereby, exist a robust degree of
equality among the participants of such an economic order.
One of the main
arguments for democracy is epistemological. Democracy, unlike other
systems of governance, has epistemic virtue for when all participate
in the framing of decisions it is possible through free and equal
deliberation to incorporate all the accessible information needed for
a relatively rational allocation of preferences.
There is nothing
inherent to economic governance that renders less force to this
argument as when applied to the political domain.
A decentralised
federation of worker owned and managed industries would be best at
incorporating all accessible information needed for a relatively
efficient production, distribution and allocation of resources
because it would be thoroughly democratic. That is not to suggest
that such a society would be a rationalist heaven in some absolutist
Laplacian sense for such a society would be required to confront the
pervasive effects of uncertainty like any other.
So we might say that of
Marxist centralised systems of planning, corporate dominated society,
free market nirvana, none would be more rational than anarchism for
none is nearly as participatory.
Feel free to call this
naïve optimism if you like. To paraphrase Princess Leia, it's our
only hope.
(Source)